I was born in 1948, at the foot of an enchanted mountain whose spirit enjoins me to rise higher

Ordinary citizen, empathetic contemplator (maybe a little too empathetic to be fully comfortable in the world, as it is). Don't look for academic credentials; this guy has none, save those gained over the course of many interesting (and, at times, difficult) life chapters, spent surviving on a shoestring budget.

Followers

Monday, November 23, 2015

Replace the word "landlord" - a semantic relic - with less intimidating synonyms anywhere possible

Before I say anything, let me assure the reader,  I know the word "landlord" is not going to go away anytime soon.  People will use it in everyday conversation because it's what they've become accustomed to using.  The official use of words in government regulations, however, can - and often is - changed by decree, if the old usage is considered, somehow, retrograde.  Language evolves with usage and the meanings attached to words can shift with time.  The need for semantic upgrade in official documents is evident when one compares old versions of laws, specific to particular considerations, with the current form that has evolved over the years from those original forms.   Sometimes, the reason a law is upgraded is because the old language is not congruent with the way we speak about the subject involved in modern parlance.  In yet other cases, new aspects of constitutionality are brought to light by bright minds, requiring an upgrade in the way law concerning that subject is interpreted.  A more subtle form of outdatedness in legal semantics occurs when law fails to keep pace with evolution in social constructs or social norms.  This writing addresses itself to the question of whether the word, "landlord", suitably reflects our society's ongoing movement toward inclusiveness and the need to reconcile the strong and the weak under one flag, in accordance with the aspirations laid out in our national constitution.

Though we don't often use them - at least, as yet - there are a number of synonyms for "landlord" that we should start getting used to using in any documents that carry legal authority - city regulations, rental contracts, court judgments, et. al.   Consider the following:  "lessor", "housing provider", "property owner", even "rentor" (an archaic, but useful, word with neutral power connotations).

The origins of the word "landlord" go back to times preceding Europe's industrial revolution, when tenant farmers, routinely referred to as peasants, were all too often subjected to extremely onerous  extractions of the product of their toil, for the right to continue living on lands owned by wealthy families.  The person holding title to the land they lived and worked would demand to be addressed by their often illiterate tenants as either, "M'Lord" or "M'Lady", so that the requisite differential in status might be abundantly clear, right from the outset.  Failure to do so would be an expression of unforgivable effrontery. A very typical pictorial representation of a peasant petitioning consideration from a lord is that of a man clutching his cap anxiously with both hands in front of him, hunched over in a posture of supplication, as if his very life, and that of his family, depended on it as, indeed, it very often did.

Once the Industrial Revolution began to fuel the almost insatiable need for a vast array of products during the most active years of European empire growth across the globe, peasants were no longer chained to the land they grew up on.  Anyone of any useful age who could be employed in any entity, private or public, engaged in this unprecedented expansion of sovereignty over foreign lands.  No country could hope to be part of this rush to empire without being willing to field a large enough navy and army to spearhead and protect new fronts of expansion.  This required men, equipment, materials and equipment, the provision for which drew heavily on populations previously locked in land deals with those that lorded it over them.  Males of a previously inescapable lowly status now had a plethora of different options they could pursue, not just at home, but across the world.

Though their housing realities no longer approximated the primitive conditions from which most had extracted themselves, those they now rented from in cities were still called "landlords", since it was customary and no other word arose as a reasonable alternative.  Indeed, deferring to custom, the word insinuated itself into law, even though those it referred to bore little resemblance to the original lords of the land such former peasants had left behind.  Even those who were fortunate enough to rise to much higher relative status, still referred to those they paid rent to as their landlords.

Very conveniently for those who owned and rented out premises, the word "landlord" crossed the Atlantic with nary a dent in its hull.  Not even the War of Independence lent reason enough for lexicographers to float an alternative more in line with the egalitarian aspirations of the Founders.  I say "conveniently" because higher extractions of rent are possible when subtle inferences, inherent in the structure of the rental relationship, induce the tenant to feel inferior to the one who owns the property being rented out.  It is the rarest of tenants who in no way fears the person who holds the power to obliterate his/her tenuous grip on security (which, for most tenants, hardly qualifies as security).  For the so-called free market to work the way it's supposed to, buyer and seller have to be on a level psychological playing field with one another.  Price point resistance on the part of the buyer needs to match the profit incentive projected by the seller.

That felicitous condition would be noticeably advanced if the word "landlord" were to be replaced by a less inherently intimidating synonym, wherever possible, in whatever writing governs affairs in the business of renting - legislation, contracts, court documents, judgments, et al. In time, the new usage would start to be reflected in the press and in general speech.  I don't, for one moment, think that a change such as this would do much good on its own; it needs to be part of a much wider set of measures applied to the situation to make rent pricing more like Walmart pricing.

In the meantime, here we are today, with rents being charged that completely deflate the hopes and dreams of young adults.  As for seniors who are forced by circumstance to rent and facing increasing difficulty finding adequately-paying work in the job market, the results of being priced out of one's home can be very grim - homelessness, depression, illness and an untimely death are common stories.  When accused of extortion, property owners are quick to claim justification, on the basis that they are just doing business the American way, breaking no laws in the process.  Maybe so, but should we just let the matter rest there and offer nothing, in response?  Clearly, I, for one, don't think so.  In fact, I think it grossly irresponsible to limply capitulate to the current situation.

I'd like to be able to "read the tea leaves", as they say, but the number of bets I've made that have come true suggests I'm not very good at that.  So when I say that I sense a change in the air, with respect to the public attitude toward rent prices and rent conditions, better take it with a grain of salt.
On the other hand, when I was growing up in South Africa, I would insist to my conservatively-minded parents that the days of "apartheid" were numbered, to which assertion they would respond with unvarnished derision, calling it Pollyanna thinking.  Those who keep up with African affairs know how that turned out.  So here's hoping that what happened to the psychological differentials in South Africa - specifically, their wholesale implosion - might occur in the rental market in the USA, in the not-too-distant future.

Monday, November 2, 2015

Lateral assistance - very important, very under-rated

Individuals of conscience - those who cannot help but care about the condition of others, relative to the comfort they, themselves, are enjoying - are often moved to want to share what they have in excess of their own needs.  Simple enough, nevertheless, they're also often perplexed about how best to disburse what it is they want to give away.

 Deciding how to give away significant amounts of one thing or another that you have to others who might need that thing, in a way that leaves one satisfied that the highest good has been achieved by that action, can be surprisingly difficult.  Will the recipients be made more empowered by the giving, or will they have been made more dependent by the time the initial utility of the gift drops off?  Will intermediaries extract more than is fair?  Will vital peripheral structures and local exchange systems be undermined, to the eventual detriment of the surrounding community's sustainability?  Can I trust those with whom I will be obliged to interact to act honestly and honorably?  What conditions or expectations, if any, should attach to the giving?  These, and many others, are the questions that complicate the kind of giving that those who aspire to being thought of as philanthropists typically face.  For the purposes of this essay, I will refer to that kind of giving as vertical giving - from one much more wealthy to some multiple of others who are very much poorer.  Actually, if one were to get really technical about the number and relative wealth of the recipients, you'd probably call it vectoral giving whose degree could be graphically represented.  Giving with a relatively high degree of interpersonal connection and mild wealth differential would have a low vectoral gradient, while typical philanthropic giving by the ultra-wealthy to thousands of unknowns in another country, deemed less developed, through a large organization, would have a vectoral gradient pretty close to 90°.  Many high-profile organizations dominate the field of charitable giving .  A lot of what they take in goes toward highly compelling advertising, solicitation activities and sustained follow-up.  Their presence in the public eye is so compelling that the, arguably, greater social value and viability of other options for delivering help - particularly those occurring within a mild vectoral gradient - can easily be overlooked.

This observation is not meant to cast aspersions on the activities of well-established charities.  Far from it.   There are those that do indispensable work,  alleviating hunger, illness and homelessness, both here and abroad.  Nevertheless, the overall record of that sector of the social charity establishment is paternalistic, effectively undermining the very reasoning that would lead the recipients to become more self-reliant - the kind that arises when self-empowered people work productively with other self-empowered people to improve the communities they call "home".  Even the best of these organizations must, inevitably, run afoul of this, to some degree.  In the case of the worst offenders, the only kind of self-empowerment they promulgate is that enjoyed by career professionals looking for politically-correct, long-term financial security.    No small number of well-researched investigations have shown that negative social indicators, particularly with respect to relative poverty, remain stubbornly entrenched among population groups most often targeted for such giving.  Indeed, in the worst of cases, local self-reliance has been badly undermined by the well-meaning activities of large, top-down-managed, charitable organizations.

Before we rush to judgment on the activities of large charities, however, placing all the blame on them for the persistence of poverty among those they attempt to help, we should pause to consider whether their efforts might have been more fruitful had society not used their entrance into the picture to rationalize cutting back on investment in more traditional forms of social assistance, when these organizations entered the picture to help.  The most obvious forms of traditional support I'm referring to include not just those tax-sponsored activities and institutions initiated and run by government but, also, those initiated by ordinary folks, the kind I call lateral assistance - the kind of highly personal, low-vectoral-gradient assistance rendered by people, one-to-one, within the bubble of the private sector.  Perhaps it's a simplistic analogy to make but, for a stool to be useful, it needs a minimum of three legs and, in the case of overall giving by society, no leg should be considered as having failed if the other two legs hadn't performed close to as well.  When it comes to the sharing of resources, the legs I'm referring to are registered charities, government action and lateral sharing.

What kind of help, specifically, falls within what I consider to be lateral assistance?  Basically, any kind of giving where, 1.), the giver and the receiver fall under some kind of umbrella - a family, a friendship, a social club, an organization, a congregation, an ethic identity, a neighborhood or a general income bracket, for instance - that has the effect of conferring upon them the status of equality and, (2.), the giver and the receiver share a bond of reciprocal concern for one another.

Why is this form of help so important to society?  Let's go through a shortlist that clearly differentiates lateral assistance from the more vertical types of help offered by governments licensed charities.

*The relatively deeper perception, on the part of the giver, into the complex nature of the potential receiver's life situation, allowing the giver to better assess the needs of that person and then tailor the giving more precisely to the needs of the receiver and, by such means, conserve funds available for providing such assistance
*Such help can be delivered in a timely way
*The delivery of the help is not impeded by an application process that might either intimidate, discourage or disqualify the person needing such help, as might be the case with some organization or government agency
*The potential for reciprocity, at some later date, is inherent to such giving
*The back-and-forth nature of this form of giving creates strong interpersonal bonds, in turn, strengthening society
*There is no lower limit to this form of sharing, as there is with institutional giving and government assistance
*There is no past-record, exclusionary factor that might be attached to the recipient that would completely block him/her from receiving assistance from a benefactor, particularly within the cocoon of a blood- or love relationship
*Such giving constitutes the largest form of help to individuals needing assistance in the buying of a home or the starting of a small business, among other things of social importance

As invaluable as lateral assistance may be, it is not an easy thing for government to create programs designed to promote the existence of it.  The biggest tool in the box - that of being able to compel parties to do this or that, if they wish to do one thing or another - is useless.  You can't compel people to exhibit the kind of decency that leads one to identify with another's needs, to the point of actually acting to render such help.  Does that mean that people in government should just give up on the idea of promoting lateral assistance?  I don't think so.  There is much benefit that government stands to gain by helping to increase the incidence of lateral assistance within the society it serves.  Every person who doesn't need to turn to government for assistance because someone within his peer group came forward with the right amount of help when it was of best use, translates into an incremental benefit for government.  Millions and millions of such people helped each year constitute a huge diminution of the demand for public assistance, along with a massive investment in future prospect, across the board.

One idea that comes to mind is made possible by the enormous leap in registering ability afforded the government by huge advances in information technology.  The old excuse that charitable giving counts toward tax deductibility only if the source of income from which it springs is greater than some arbitrary cutoff point, simply because the paperwork involved would be too voluminous to extend the same gratitude toward lower earners is no longer valid.  If the government were to expect of itself the same kind of rigor, creativity and flexibility found throughout the private sector these days, owing to great advances in IT, it could make deductible any amount of qualifying and properly registered lateral assistance, given to another, unconditionally without ulterior financial designs.  Giver and receiver would have to know one another personally.  How could such a thing be vetted for honesty? By giving each giver wishing to participate, a monitorable digital account reserved solely for such purpose, from which the recipients, using passwords, could withdraw amounts, at leisure, up to a defined limit.  Giver and recipient would have to qualify as peers under whatever qualifying umbrella accords them status as peers.

Another thing government could do is air public service ads promoting the value of lateral giving to society - the sort of advertising of good personal behavior that the state of Utah engages in to such good effect.

Nothing should be done, however, without first undertaking a careful analysis of how much good is currently being delivered by lateral giving and what kind of additional social returns could be had by investing public moneys in expanding rates of such giving.